[StBernard] FDR and the Great Deflation

Westley Annis Westley at da-parish.com
Tue Oct 7 08:39:06 EDT 2008


FDR and the Great Deflation
by David R. Stokes

The period between late 1929 and the beginning of the
1940s is, of course, known as the Great Depression.
But in a real sense, it could be called the Great De-
pressions. There was more than one massive downturn
in all things economic during those days of deprivation.

Five years after Franklin Delano Roosevelt spoke so
eloquently about "fear itself" - and then began to ful-
fill his promise of "experimentation" (as opposed to
an actual plan), things were really no better than the
day he took office. His "hundred days" of frenetic
legislation gave way to years of false starts and faded
hopes.

In early 1938, unemployment was at the 1931 level of
17.4 % and the Dow Industrial Average - at 121 - was
still less than half of its 1929 high. The Dow would
not actually return to pre-crash levels until Dwight
D. Eisenhower was well into his first presidential
term.

Amity Shlaes, in her fascinating book - a must read
these days - The Forgotten Man: A New History of the
Great Depression, gives us a snapshot of the situa-
tion half a decade into the politics, policies, and
promises of the New Deal:

"The country was now at an odd moment. There was a
new sense of permanence about the Depression. Being
poor was no longer a passing event - it was beginning
to seem like a way of life."

What started as a panic in 1929 soon morphed into
something more sinister, deadly, and often overlooked:
deflation. As money became scarcer, prices fell. De-
clining prices, if allowed to continue for long, tend
to lead to a dangerous downward spiral of negatives -
things like falling profits, closing businesses and
factories, shrinking employment and incomes, and in-
creasing defaults on loans by companies and individuals.

Deflation is the monster - the category 5 economic
storm - to watch out for and guard against.

Early on during the Great Depression, housing values,
though not starting the problem, became a leading in-
dicator of the severity of the crisis. As prices moved
down, homeowners found themselves with homes worth less
than the mortgage amount. This led to a deflationary
meltdown.

Sound familiar?

There are two knee-jerk things that both Herbert Hoover
and Franklin Roosevelt did that actually ensured that
the Depression would have a long run. First, Hoover
stifled free trade when he, against the advice of many
economists and business leaders, signed a protectionist
tariff (Smoot-Hawley) bill. He ignored doomsday warn-
ings that this "would spell economic isolation" and lead
to the "most severe depression ever experienced." Sadly,
those warnings came true.

And both Hoover and Roosevelt fought the Depression by
raising taxes.

Mr. Hoover gave us the Revenue Act of 1932, which burden-
ed people already having a hard time holding on to homes
and making ends meet. With deflation, dollars were worth
more, so the government was taking these increasingly
rare and more valuable dollars out of the hands of the
people, in many cases sealing their financial doom.

Franklin Roosevelt wanted to change society through tax
policy. He seldom met a tax he didn't like. The presi-
dent clearly cultivated his image as an enemy of the
"great accumulation of wealth" and the protector of the
"people" from corporations, utilities, and other usual
suspects who become convenient rhetorical targets during
times of economic crisis and confusion.

As the Great Depression lingered, Americans languished.
Washington tended to do the wrong thing at the wrong
time. As people watched the president, with a complicit
Congress, raise taxes they wondered: "With business so
hard, why make it harder?"

Conventional historical wisdom - the legend and lore of
days gone by - suggests that Hoover was a "do-nothing"
president who fiddled (better: fished) while the country
burned. Then came Roosevelt on his white horse - a man
of action (like his distant relative who also served as
president). He saved the nation - and everyone lived
happily ever after until he had to save us again - from
the Nazis.

But, as Shlaes points out, the two men actually had much
in common:

"Hoover and Roosevelt were alike in several regards. Both
preferred to control events and people. Both underesti-
mated the strength of the American economy. Both doubted
its ability to right itself in a storm. Hoover mistrust-
ed the stock market. Roosevelt mistrusted it more.

Both presidents overestimated the value of government
planning.

And both men doctored the economy habitually. Hoover was
a constitutionalist and took pains to intervene within
the rules - but his interventions were substantial.
Roosevelt cared little for constitutional niceties and
believed they blocked progress. His remedies were on a
greater scale and often inspired by socialist or fascist
models abroad."

Deflation impacted the American worker the hardest. In
times of even moderate inflation wages increase (along
with prices). But during a deflationary cycle, wages
either remain the same, or drop, or worse - disappear
entirely. It brings to mind one of the more morbid say-
ings from those days: "The Depression isn't that bad if
you have a job."

The fact is that the crash of 1929 did not cause the
Great Depression - at least, not right away. The prec-
ipitating force triggering the cascading crisis that
gripped the world back then was deflation, something
that Hoover overlooked - and Roosevelt missed completely.

So - why, then, was FDR elected four times? Well, in
1932 he was just plain better at campaigning than Pre-
sident Hoover - and people were upset and wanted change.

In 1940, the storm clouds of war certainly worked in
Roosevelt's favor. And by 1944, the people were not
going to vote a sitting president out of office during
a time of war (bearing in mind that an overwhelming
number of Americans supported the war effort).

1936, though, is an enigma. Amity Shlaes suggests that
FDR invented a "new kind of interest-group politics."
Many Americans became part of a movement that "demanded
something from government." Also, the initiatives
developed during Roosevelt's first term increased federal
spending. For the first time in our nation's history the
national government spent more than all the states com-
bined.

And 1936 was really the first election year where feder-
ally driven entitlements - a persistent challenge ever
since - were part of the national experience. Enter
the politics of the trough.

In other words, Franklin Delano Roosevelt was successful
because he convinced enough people he was trying to do
something for them. The record shows that he did not
really do all that much, but such facts tend to fall short
when countered by a compelling narrative.

"Bold, persistent, experimentation," that's what Mr.
Roosevelt promised on day one of his presidency. One
wonders if anyone could be elected today by saying, in
effect, "I will keep making stuff up until something
works." But FDR was actually that good at politics.

As an example of FDR's experimental economic savvy, one
day he announced to his staff that he was considering
raising the price of an ounce of gold by twenty-one cents.
When someone inquired as to the rational behind that
figure the president replied: "because it's three times
seven. It's a lucky number."

Imagine what Oliver Stone could do with Franklin D.
Roosevelt if he gave it a try.






More information about the StBernard mailing list